首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   232篇
  免费   12篇
财政金融   35篇
工业经济   10篇
计划管理   35篇
经济学   89篇
运输经济   1篇
旅游经济   4篇
贸易经济   17篇
农业经济   16篇
经济概况   33篇
信息产业经济   4篇
  2023年   1篇
  2020年   5篇
  2019年   7篇
  2018年   5篇
  2017年   8篇
  2016年   8篇
  2015年   6篇
  2014年   11篇
  2013年   18篇
  2012年   12篇
  2011年   19篇
  2010年   11篇
  2009年   13篇
  2008年   14篇
  2007年   12篇
  2006年   22篇
  2005年   7篇
  2004年   10篇
  2003年   7篇
  2002年   4篇
  2001年   2篇
  2000年   6篇
  1999年   2篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   5篇
  1996年   1篇
  1995年   4篇
  1993年   2篇
  1991年   1篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1988年   1篇
  1985年   2篇
  1982年   1篇
  1981年   1篇
  1979年   1篇
  1976年   1篇
  1975年   2篇
  1973年   2篇
  1972年   1篇
  1971年   2篇
  1968年   2篇
排序方式: 共有244条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
51.
This paper investigates how exchange rates affect Japanese exports. This is difficult because many of Japan's exports are used to produce goods for re-export. An appreciation in the importing country that decreases exports can decrease its imported inputs from Japan. To avoid this bias we examine consumption exports. Using a panel dataset of Japan's consumption exports to 17 countries over the 1988–2009 period, we find exchange rate elasticities of about one. These results indicate that the large swings in the value of the yen over the last decade have caused large swings in the volume of Japanese exports.  相似文献   
52.
A spatio-temporal model of house prices in the USA   总被引:3,自引:0,他引:3  
This paper provides an empirical analysis of changes in real house prices in the USA using State level data. It examines the extent to which real house prices at the State level are driven by fundamentals such as real per capita disposable income, as well as by common shocks, and determines the speed of adjustment of real house prices to macroeconomic and local disturbances. We take explicit account of both cross-sectional dependence and heterogeneity. This allows us to find a cointegrating relationship between real house prices and real per capita incomes with coefficients (1,−1)(1,1), as predicted by the theory. We are also able to identify a significant negative effect for a net borrowing cost variable, and a significant positive effect for the State level population growth on changes in real house prices. Using this model we then examine the role of spatial factors, in particular, the effect of contiguous states by use of a weighting matrix. We are able to identify a significant spatial effect, even after controlling for State specific real incomes, and allowing for a number of unobserved common factors. We do, however, find evidence of departures from long run equilibrium in the housing markets in a number of States notably California, New York, Massachusetts, and to a lesser extent Connecticut, Rhode Island, Oregon and Washington State.  相似文献   
53.
Consider a two-commodity n-country model without inferior goods where import tariffs are the only trade barriers. In this paper we establish that the world's welfare is improved if the country with the highest tariff rate unilaterally reduce its rate to the level of the second highest country or if all the countries of the world reduce tariff rates proportionally. The second rule serves as a theoretical justification of the Kennedy and Tokyo Round Tariff Reductions.  相似文献   
54.
Fixed-point theorems for multi-valued mappings and economic equilibrium existence theorems are generalized from the viewpoint that the continuity and/or convexity assumptions on a mapping may be replaced by weaker local conditions on the vector field defined by the mapping. The generalization gives us natural conditions on individual (possibly non-ordered) preferences or aggregated demand behaviours so that we may obtain several extensions of recent results in social and game-theoretic equilibrium theories.
JEL Classification Numbers: C60, C62, C72, D50, D51.  相似文献   
55.
We examine how ability‐screening affects demand for education and the shape of an optimal education system. Explicitly incorporating gradual screening by education into the model, we illustrate how individuals of different abilities decide to stay in education or drop out. Gradual screening induces low‐ability individuals to receive over‐education, reducing the net benefit obtained from education by society as a whole, as well as such individuals. A mixed education system, in which public education is provided before private education, is superior to a wholly private system, in terms of both efficiency and equity, because it reduces the over‐education of low‐ability individuals.  相似文献   
56.
57.
ABSTRACT

This study highlights the importance of founders’ human capital on firms’ absorptive capacity for explaining the external knowledge sourcing (licensing-in and joint R&D) of start-up firms, using panel data from original questionnaire surveys conducted in Japan. The results of a probit model with an endogenous regressor show that firms managed by founders with a high level of specific human capital, measured as prior innovation experience and industry-specific work experience, tend to engage in external knowledge sourcing because of their superior absorptive capacity. The findings indicate that this type of human capital also promotes research and development (R&D) investment. Contrariwise, this study finds that firms managed by founders with a high level of general human capital, measured as educational attainment, tend to invest more in R&D, which enhances their absorptive capacity and thereby promotes external knowledge sourcing. Finally, the implications of these findings are discussed from the perspective of public policy.  相似文献   
58.
Democracy and the Variability of Economic Performance   总被引:3,自引:0,他引:3  
Sah (1991) conjectured that more centralized societies should have more volatile economic performances than less centralized ones. We show in this paper that this is true both for cross–country and within–country variability in growth rates. It is also true for some measures of policies. Finally, we show that both the best and worst performers in terms of growth rates are more likely to be autocracies. We argue that the evidence in the paper is consistent with the theoretical implications in Sah and Stiglitz (1991) and Rodrik (1999a).  相似文献   
59.
Indonesia was deeply affected by the 1997–1998 crisis, more so than its East Asian neighbors. Its economic contraction was deeper and more prolonged. It was the only one to experience a (temporary) loss of macroeconomic control. It also suffered “twin crises,” in the sense that its serious economic and financial problems were accompanied by regime collapse. Consequently, recovery was a slow and complex process, as new institutions had to be created, and old ones reformed under successive short‐lived administrations. But this process is largely over. The directly elected president with a strong popular mandate is in power. The new institutional framework for economic policy‐making is in place. Macroeconomic stability has been restored. Although growth has yet to return to pre‐crisis levels, by 2004 per capita income and poverty incidence had recovered to levels prevailing in the mid‐1990s, and in the circumstances economic recovery has arguably proceeded about as quickly as could reasonably have been expected.  相似文献   
60.
The spirit of capitalism, stock market bubbles and output fluctuations   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
This paper presents a representative agent model in which stock market bubbles cause output fluctuations. Assuming that utility depends directly on wealth, we show that stock market bubbles arise if the marginal utility of wealth does not decline to zero as wealth goes to infinity. Bubbles can affect output positively or negative depending on whether the production function exhibits increasing or decreasing returns to scale. In sunspot equilibria, the bursting of a bubble is followed by a sharp decline in output one period later. Various numerical examples are given to illustrate the behavior of stochastic bubbles and the relationship between bubbles and output.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号